9.3 The Lagrange formalism for the example of the consumption problem

We are now solving the already known problem of the budget optimum: Maximize utility U x,y with a given budget B, when the prices of goods are px and py. For the utility function, non-saturation and concavity apply.

max x,yU x,y under the condition that xpx + ypy = B.

We form the Lagrange function

𝕃 x,y,λ = U x,y + λ xpx + ypy B

and the first order conditions:

d dxU x,y + λpx = 0 (9.1) d dyU x,y + λpy = 0 (9.2) xpx + ypy B = 0 (9.3)

The FOC 3 represents the second order constraint. The other two are transformed by adding λpx and λpy, respectively

d dxU x,y = λpx (9.4) d dyU x,y = λpy (9.5)

and then divide the equations with each other. This cancels λ.

d dxU x,y d dyU x,y = px py (9.6)

The resulting equation represents the central point of the solution. It represents a relationship between the marginal utility ratio and the price ratio.
1) The price ratio px py is the slope of the budget line.
2) The marginal utility ratio d dxU x,y d dyU x,y is the marginal rate of substitution, i.e. the slope of the isoquant.
3) The maximum is reached where the slope of the budget line is equal to the slope of the isoquant and lies on the budget line.
4) Now take equation (4) and the second order constraint and solve the system of two equations for x and y.
Equation (4) represents an intuitively very plausible heuristic. If good x has a high marginal utility, then the willingness to pay (price) for this good is also high. If the marginal utility is low, then the price paid for it is also low. Thus, the higher the value that a consumer assigns to a good, the higher the price he is willing to pay for it.
As a notation for the partial derivative, the indexing of the function name with the variable in respect to which it is differentiated d dxU x,y = Ux x,y, has often been adopted. Then, equation (4) is written as

Ux x,y Uy x,y = px py, (9.7)

where the index of the function is to be read as a derivative and the index of the price variable as a simple classification.

The implicit function theorem

The slope of the isoquant can be explained by the implicit function theorem. This theorem states that the slope of an isoquant is the negative ratio of the partial derivatives. To be more precise:
If F x,y is a function with d dyF x0,y0 0 and f x is a function that keeps the level of F constant, i.e. F x,f x = c, then:

fx 0 = d dxF x0,y0 d dyF x0,y0

where y0 = f x0. The idea of the proof goes back to the multidimensional chain rule.

c F x,f x 0 d dxF x,f x + d dyF x,f xfx


(c) by Christian Bauer
Prof. Dr. Christian Bauer
Chair of monetary economics
Trier University
D-54296 Trier
Tel.: +49 (0)651/201-2743
E-mail: Bauer@uni-trier.de
URL: https://www.cbauer.de